Wednesday 13 March 2013

Ellen MacArthur's boat as a small, zero production economy


Ellen MacArthur (EM) is doing a great job as the poster girl for the circular economy and is clearly very passionate about the subject. Where does that passion come from?

I think I've seen references to her comparing the enclosed nature of her round the world voyages to the planet in general and how this awakened her realisation of the finite nature of resources and the need to change global production and consumption patterns. But how realistic is this comparison?

At its simplest level we might think of EM's boat as a small, zero production economy. In this economy EM is given an initial endowment of resources which she manages/depletes during the course of her voyage.

An alternative model of an economy would add production, which would enable the economy to apply different combinations of capital and labour to its initial endowment thereby producing new goods/resources. In this way, the supply of resources available to the economy is no longer fixed but can be grown through production. Productivity improvements over time enable the economy to grow (ad infinitum).

Which of these two models is more appropriate for the global economy? This question really boils down to whether or not resource scarcity is actually a problem at the global level.

Environmentalists say of course resources are finite. But this isn't really true in any practical sense (known commodity reserves are at all time highs as is commodity production). The US shale gas boom and the recent news that Japan has found a new way to extract energy from methane hydrate are examples of how the supply of resources isn't fixed but can be grown through new production methods (a new application of labour and capital to our initial endowment).

Does this really matter for the circular economy? Not if it has an alternative justification, such as minimising environmental impacts or reducing business costs, but it is not necessarily as straightforward as some might expect.

Monday 11 March 2013

Market failures in waste prevention


Defra has today published a call for evidence for its waste prevention programme. I haven't yet read the whole document but one thing which immediately raised my hackles was spotting a section on "market failures". I personally think that policy makers are all too quick to refer to market failure when actually these either don't exist or are preferable to the far more prevalent alternative of government failure.

The first one Defra refers to is the case of "environmental externalities" - fair enough at first glance. It then says this is manifested through the full cost of waste not being paid by producers. On the contrary, businesses do pay for the waste they produce (and pay prices which are higher than the externalities would actually suggest). In the household sector this incentive is of course missing but I don't suppose for one minute Defra is proposing the politically unpalatable introduction of pay-as-you-throw.

"Split incentives" are another policy makers' favourite. The example used here is of a manufacturer designing out waste to the benefit of consumers or local authorities (presumably packaging). But the manufacturer benefits from not having to pay for avoided material inputs. The landfill tax escalator and the commodity boom of the past decade have both shown that manufacturers respond to price signals and reduce waste.

"Information failures". This is where policy makers expose their belief that they are better placed to spot bottom-line savings than actual businesses themselves. Not true in my book.

"Behavioural barriers". Here Defra seems to think that firms/individuals discount the future too heavily and so are unwilling to take longer term actions. However, individuals must take decisions under conditions of extreme uncertainty and their choice of discount rate may actually lead to far more rational choices than Defra officials could come up with.

"Financial barriers". Businesses/individuals may be credit constrained. For me, this is just the real world where financial choices have to be made between competing priorities and, to the horror of Defra officials, waste prevention may not be at the top of the list.

Overall, I think that Defra (and its various consultants) tend to underestimate the opportunity costs associated with waste prevention measures. Implementing waste prevention often has a positive financial return. But so does investment in productive business activity/output. It is not necessarily irrational for businesses to choose to invest in production rather than waste prevention, but policy makers often seem to miss this point.

Tuesday 5 March 2013

Should one size EU policy fit all?


Further to yesterday's post, it occurs to me that in the area of global climate change policy we recognise that poorer developing countries have lower per capita greenhouse gas impacts and so should be allowed to develop without binding carbon constraints, while at the same time developed countries with higher per capita emissions should cut back stringently.

In the case of EU waste policy however, we find that the poorer Eastern European States have lower environmental impacts from their waste management systems but must have high cost Northern European-style systems imposed on them straight away (perhaps before they can afford them?).

Would it not be fairer to allow the Eastern States only to introduce recycling and recovery infrastructure as their waste generation increases, while at the same time placing stronger waste reduction requirements on northern Member States?

Monday 4 March 2013

Romanian municipal waste performance better than Germany

Via @Defrawaste I see that Eurostat has published the latest EU figures for municipal waste management.

Poor old Romania (as well as other Eastern Member States) often gets singled out for its poor performance as it landfills 99% of its municipal waste. Terrible, I'm sure we'd all agree. But another, often overlooked factor, is that waste generation per person is much lower there than in some of the richer Member States with more sophisticated approaches to waste management.

In fact, if we were to include the avoided production emissions from lower waste generation in Romania we would find that net emissions from its municipal waste would be lower than for Germany, which only sends 1% of its municipal waste to landfill. (I have cheekily used Defra emission assumptions for the UK when checking these figures, which would lead to the assumption that Romanian landfills are managed in accordance with Landfill Directive requirements for capping/gas management which may or may not be accurate.)

As anyone au fait with the waste hierarchy knows this is because the environmental gains from waste minimisation dwarf any emission savings from switching between different forms of waste management once that waste has been generated. The sector awaits Defra's National Waste Prevention Plan due in December with interest.